It's official. We're back! As you may have noticed we've been quite inactive for a long period of time (blame us....we're procrastinator and good at it). However, while this blog fell into prolonged hibernation, we were kept busy elsewhere. Yudo was (and is still) occupied by his research projects, while also having a blog of his own. Meanwhile, I have just finished my studies, in my spare time also moonlights as a guest DJ at the cafe next door, and am now in the early stages of my reserch projects.
Then, some unknown and unseen force(s?) drove us back to revisit this blog. Yudo got the ball rolling by posting the result of his recent research on labor issues. One thing led to another, we thought why not revitalize the whole look for the blog? So we did a full cosmetic change, cleaning our blog from spammers, remove unnecessary stuffs, etc. Hope you'll like the end result.
Finally, as a bonus we present you with Thin Lizzy's "The Boys Are Back in Town". We think this song is appropriate for the occasion, enjoy :)
Thursday, November 20, 2008
.....And We're Back!
Posted by Pasha at 5:22 AM 1 comments
Saturday, November 15, 2008
More on labor issue
This posting leads me to re-read again what I wrote and I stumbled with this fact. First, unit wage cost became less sensitive after the crisis period to employment. In the pre-crisis period, One percent increase in nominal wage cost in the TCF industry was associated by 0.25 percent employment reduction. Yet in the post-crisis period, the one-percent change in wage cost was associated by 0.09 percent employment change.
Second: while at the same time, speed of adjustment in labor demand due to a shock is getting longer in the post-crisis period.
“…Comparing between the pre and post crisis, we can say that the post-crisis labor market environment in the industry is much tighter that the pre-crisis environment. Two explanations can be offered here. First rising uncertainty in demand for output leads firms to keep the existing level of employment, despite a growing demand for output (e.g. footwear industry immediately after the crisis). Second, slow adjustment can be attributed to surging adjustment cost (i.e. firing cost). Therefore pointing high dismissal cost as an explanation behind this is quite justified…”
This situation applies only to permanent job in textile industry- part of formal employment. So given this, I cannot say that the impact of wage cost on formal employment will be the same as in the case of permanent workers. Yet this gives indication that even though firms' compliance rate to other labour regulations (non minimum wage) may be low, these have backwash effect for permanent job creation and, in turn, secure job.
Posted by This Blog at 10:51 PM 0 comments
Labels: labor economics, labor market
Does trade-off between MW and employment levels apply to All?
Ape in his comment argued that “the wage-formal employment trade off is apparent” but paradoxically this is not the case of textile industry-one of labor-intensive industry and supposedly is much more sensitive to minimum wages (MW). Based on Sakernas data, such trade-off is absent indeed. From the figure below, we can clearly visualize that the percentage of formal employment followed closely MW.
Real value added (trillion Rp)
If the formal sector employment starts to grow amid stringent EPL, it does not necessarilly mean that EPL is not an obstacle (or has less impact). Solid domestic output demand may compensate the impact of EPL on employment. But if we relaxe this, perhaps we may see that formal employment grows faster. But it is better for me to say that i don't know exactly which one is the main obstacle (MW or EPL) on employment. But based on my study in textile industry, the employers are concerned much more on the latter (EPL) rather than the former (MW).
Conclusion:
The impact of MW on employment levels seems to vary within formal jobs. I don't say that MW does not bring an adverse impact on employment levels. Yet growing output demand recently is likely to compensate the impact of MW. MW and EPL are determinants affecting input cost of firms and in turn labor demand. But output demand is another driver affecting labor demand as well. Another issue is about data reliability-well I don’t know exactly how to get around this issue.
Update
this is one more
Posted by This Blog at 3:27 PM 1 comments
How technical change affects the employment levels
“…fiber industry and spinning industry are characterized as relatively capital-intensive industry. On the other hand, the apparel industry and footwear industry are classified as labor-intensive industry. This category is reflected by the figure X. The capital intensity of textiles industry (left-axis) is far above the capital intensity of apparel and footwear industry (right-axis). However, several trends are worth pointing. First the 1998 economic crisis has brought a significant change in the factor intensity. In three sub sectors, the capital intensity increased dramatically in the crisis period. The main driver was because the crisis led to a surging capital price and massive-scale of job dismissal (i.e. compositional change).
green: textile; red:apparel and black: footwear
In other words, slowing employment growth in textile industry already took place before the crisis and, surely, before the rapid increase in MW. I’m thinking that perhaps other labour regulations affecting much employment growth instead of MW.
Posted by This Blog at 9:53 AM 4 comments
Labels: employment, technical change